Agricultural Policy in Kenya

Policy Brief 06
By Patrick O. Alila and Rosemary Atieno
January 2006

Agriculture is the backbone of the Kenyan economy. It contributes approximately 25% of GDP, employing 75% of the national labour force. Over 80% of the Kenyan population live in rural areas and make a living, directly or indirectly, from agriculture.
The sector is important for poverty reduction since the most vulnerable groups, such as pastoralists, the landless, and subsistence farmers, depend on agriculture as their main source of livelihoods. Growth in agriculture therefore can be expected to have a significant impact on a larger section of the population than any other sector. Likewise, policies affecting the performance of agriculture have important implications for the economy as a whole.

 

Agriculture, Growth and Poverty Reduction in Ethiopia

Policy Brief 05
By Amdissa Teshome
January 2006

Trade-offs between growth and poverty reduction and the role of agriculture are major contemporary issues in debates about future agricultures in Africa. In Ethiopia, this has been a long-running debate, but one that has been brought into sharper focus by the recent discussions about the second PRSP (Povery Reduction Strategy Paper) –the Plan for Accelerated and Sustainable Development to End Poverty (PASDEP). This briefing explores the policy processes surrounding PASDEP, and the implications this has for agricultural policy and rural development more broadly.

Intensification of Smallholder Agriculture in Ethiopia

Policy Brief 04
By Samuel Gebreselassie
January 2006

The prevailing orthodoxy is to see the problem of smallholder agriculture in Ethiopia strictly as a technical and resource related problem. This view identifies the low level of agricultural productivity as the key problem. In response, the government of Ethiopia has since the mid-1990s, implemented a high-profile, national technology-led extension programme. But has this worked, and what are the limitations of such a strategy

 

Food Aid and Smallholder Agriculture in Ethiopia

Policy Brief 03
By Samuel Gebreselassie
January 2006

Ethiopia has been structurally in food deficit since at least 1980. Today, Ethiopia is the world’s most food aid dependent country. The country received 795 thousand metric tonnes of food aid annually between 1990 and 1999, about 10% of total domestic grain production. This Briefing asks what have been the impacts of food aid in Ethiopia and what are the implications for future policy, and particularly the links between food aid and smallholder agriculture?

Pathways for Ethiopian Agriculture: Options and Scenarios

By Samuel Gebreselassie, Amdissa Teshome, Stephen Devereux, Ian Scoones, and Kay Sharp
Policy Brief 002

The paradox facing agricultural policy in Ethiopia was neatly encapsulated in a statement by Prime Minister Meles Zenawi, in 2000: “The agricultural sector remains our Achilles heel and source of vulnerability. … Nonetheless, we remain convinced that agricultural-based development remains the only source of hope for Ethiopia.

” The reality is that most Ethiopians continue to struggle to make their living from smallholder farming, despite low returns, high risks, and the evident inability of agriculture to provide even a reliable subsistence income, let alone a ‘take-off’ to poverty reduction and sustainable economic growth.

Policy-makers and analysts, both national and expatriate, have vacillated between arguing for increased investment in smallholder farming, commercialising agriculture, or abandoning unviable smallholder agriculture by promoting diversification or urbanisation instead. It is often remarked that, if Ethiopia can solve the profound challenges facing its agriculture sector, the lessons will be applicable in many other parts of Africa.

Land, Land Policy and Smallholder Agriculture in Ethiopia

By Samuel Gebreselassie
Policy Brief 001

Land_Land_Policy_and_Smallholder_Agriculture_in_EthiopiaLand and land tenure is a hot policy issue in Ethiopia. Three key issues are raised – farm size and fragmentation and the question of what is a ‘viable’ farm unit; tenure security and whether lack of land registration/certi. Cation or titling undermines investment in productivity improvements; and finally the issue land markets andwhether imperfectly functioning markets constrain opportunities for land consolidation, investment and agricultural growth.

Farm size, land fragmentation andsmallholder production
Ethiopia is a country of smallholder agriculture. In the 2000 cropping season, 87.4 % of rural households operated less than 2 hectares; whereas 64.5 % of them cultivated farms less than one hectare; while 40.6 % operated land sizes of 0.5 hectare and less. Such small farms are fragmented on average into 2.3 plots. The average farm size can generate only about 50% of the minimum income required for the average farm household to lead a life out of poverty, if current levels of farm productivity and price structures remain constant. Such farmers have little or no surplus for investment and for input purchase.

The increasing decline of farm size also leads to a reduction of fallowing practice or shortening of fallow cycles, and rotation, with a consequence of declining soil quality and fertility in some highland areas. The average farm size is considered by many too be small to allow sustainable intensi. Cation of smallholder agriculture. The probability of adopting fertilizer and improved seeds decreases with declines in farm size. Households with relatively small farm size are generally poor in cash income, have less access to extension services and credit, and have less risk coping opportunities to take risks of rain failure, and less profitable technologies given higher transaction costs of acquisition and application of fertiliser per unit of operated land.

Déclarations des donateurs : quel rôle pour l’agriculture?

Quel est le rôle de l’agriculture aux yeux des organismes internationaux concernés par le développement agricole ? Quel rôle jouent le marché et l’état ? Ce document de synthèse examine quatre déclarations faites récemment par des organismes d’aide de premier plan et s’interroge sur la manière dont ils voient le rôle de l’agriculture dans le développement.

La politique agricole kenyane

Rôle de l’agriculture dans la lutte contre la pauvreté

L’agriculture est le moteur de l’économie kenyane. Elle contribue à environ 25 % du PIB, employant 75 % de la population active nationale. Plus de 80 % de la population kenyane est établie dans les zones rurales et vit, directement ou indirectement, de l’agriculture. Ce secteur est important pour réduire la pauvreté sachant que les groupes les plus vulnérables, comme les gardiens de troupeaux, les sans-terre et les agriculteurs de subsistance dépendent de l’agriculture, qui est leur principale ressource. On peut donc s’attendre à ce que la croissance agricole ait un impact significatif sur une portion plus large de la population que tout autre secteur. De même, les mesures politiques affectant la performance de l’agriculture ont des implications importantes pour l’économie en général.

 

 

Processus de formulation des politiques agricoles au Kenya

Au Kenya, le succès de la Stratégie de relance de l’agriculture (SRA), examinée par Future Agricultures dans son document d’information « La politique agricole kenyane », dépend des structures, acteurs et processus politiques affectant la politique agricole kenyane. Ce document d’information examine l’impact de chacun de ces facteurs sur les politiques agricoles kenyanes d’hier mais aussi d’aujourd’hui. Il resitue les différentes étapes politiques présentes dans le cadre de la SRA et vérifie si ces structures et actions sont suffisantes ou non pour la mise en oeuvre de la SRA.

Terres, politique foncière et agriculture paysanne en Éthiopie

Terre et régime foncier sont des sujets sensibles en Éthiopie. Trois problèmes cruciaux se posent : d’abord, la taille et le morcellement de l’exploitation et la question de savoir ce qu’est une exploitation « viable » ; ensuite, la sécurité foncière et savoir si le manque de cadastrage/de certification ou la définition d’unités cadastrales freinent les investissements visant à l’amélioration de la productivité ; et enfin, suivre les marchés fonciers et savoir si des marchés en évolution irrégulière réduisent les opportunités de remembrement, d’investissement et de croissance.

Issues pour l’agriculture éthiopienne : options et scénarios

Le Premier ministre éthiopien Meles Zenawi a clairement cerné le paradoxe de la politique agricole nationale en 2000 lors d’une déclaration : « L’agriculture demeure notre talon d’Achille et une source de vulnérabilité […] Nous demeurons cependant convaincus que l’agriculture est le seul espoir de développement de l’Ethiopie ». Le fait est que la plupart des Ethiopiens luttent pour vivre sur de petites exploitations agricoles, obtenant de faibles rendements, courant des risques, dans une activité incapable de leur fournir un revenu de subsistance fiable et encore moins de leur permettre de « décoller » grâce à une réduction de la pauvreté ou à une croissance économique durable. Les décideurs politiques et les observateurs, qu’ils vivent en Ethiopie ou à l’étranger, hésitent entre encourager l’investissement dans les petites exploitations, l’agriculture commerciale ou l’abandon de ces fermes familiales sans avenir, en faveur de la diversification ou de l’urbanisation. Ils soulignent souvent que, si l’Ethiopie peut résoudre les problèmes graves de son agriculture, les leçons pourront s’appliquer dans de nombreuses autres régions africaines.

Is there a future for small farms?

Achieving pro-poor growth through agriculture: the challenges

Friday, 2 December 13.00–14.30, at Overseas Development Institute, 111 Westminster Bridge Road, London SE1 7JD

Is there a future for small farms?

Speaker: Colin Poulton, Imperial College and Steve Wiggins, Overseas Development Institute

Chair: Andrew Shepherd, Overseas Development Institute

Audio (listen to the meeting)
Steve Wiggins
Colin Poulton (1)
Colin Poulton (2)
Discussion (1)
Discussion (2)

See Colin Poulton and Steve Wiggins’ presentation


You’ll need Windows Media Player to listen to these clips. You can download the correct version here

Steve Wiggins outlined the ways in which agriculture reduces poverty in low income countries – through raising farmer incomes, (above all in Africa), employment opportunities (especially in South Asia), lower food prices, and returns to land (especially in Africa) for small farmers. In Latin America agricultural growth creates opportunities in processing and food chains. There are very few countries which have industrialised without an ‘agricultural revolution’. Recent cross country econometric analysis supports the relationship between agricultural growth (and especially growth in crop yields) and poverty reduction. Alternative approaches to reducing rural poverty may be hard to come by.

Small farms have some advantages: they use land intensively, labour supervision is easier, small farmers have reservoirs of local knowledge, and benefit from producing their own food supply. The advantages of big farms, on the other hand, are knowledge of markets and technology, access to inputs and technical services, ability to cope with quality assurance, and to manage risks.Given that average farm sizes in poor countries are falling, whereas they are increasing in rich countries, the advantages of small farms may outweigh those of large farms in the developing world. Small farms are certainly not disappearing.
Nor will they disappear, agreed Colin Poulton. Their rising share – of land farmed – can be explained either by their economic advantages or by ‘market imperfections’, especially in land markets, which do not allow for easy concentration of land. Other values also attach to land – social insurance, land as a base for diversified livelihood portfolios – which encourage individuals and households to retain land even as subdivision creates smaller and smaller units. The key question, therefore, is: Are small farms still able to function as drivers of growth or are they increasingly repositories of chronic poverty?
There are strong arguments to suggest the latter, as the world becomes more hostile to small farms: commodity prices dip ever lower (though local markets may be buoyant – eg in African coastal cities); there are environmental limits to intensification; the easy technological options for yield increases may have been exhausted; HIV/AIDS has undermined both the labour force and capital stock of millions of affected agricultural households, especially in sub-Saharan Africa (although the total agricultural labour force continues to rise even here); and in Sub-Saharan Africa, again, there is no model for intensification of cereals production (the ‘green revolution’) in the context of liberalised agricultural markets. (The green revolution in Asia happened in the context of closed markets and heavy state intervention and subsidies – all of which are now effectively ‘ruled out’ by international policy.) Finally, the increasingly present supermarkets prefer large suppliers, though where small farms predominate (eg China) supermarkets have developed ways of relating to them.

On the other hand, small farms have an advantage where products require intensive and diligent labour, but if assurances on quality or environmental issues is required by the market, small farmers will find that more challenging – if not impossible. Small farmers’ ability to associate will be critical to their ability to stay in or get into markets. Both speakers agreed, however, that the prospects of marginal holdings of less than 1 hectare acting as a driver of growth are remote. Rather, attention must be paid to strengthening the linkages between agricultural and non-farm growth if households with such marginal holdings are to be lifted out of poverty. More generally, where land is equally held, agricultural growth is more likely to reduce poverty than where landholding is unequal.

What alternative is there in Africa? Where opportunities exist, both export-oriented manufacturing growth in coastal areas and growth based on minerals (the Indonesian example) can demand increased output of agriculture, as well as generate funds for investment in agriculture as a “supporter” of growth and poverty reduction. However, much of the continent is landlocked, so can’t easily get into manufacturing, nor does it have minerals.
An excellent discussion ranged over labour absorption in agriculture, the costs of getting food from the hinterland to coastal cities, and the need to focus on inland population centres too; through the need to gather data which showed that agriculture was not always the failure it is often thought to be, through discussion about the role of the state and subsidies, through to the difficulties posed by marginal farms.

In conclusion, it could be agreed that:

  • Small farms will be there for a long time to come
  • There is a need to assemble the positive picture on small farms and challenge the perception of failure
  • The links between small farms and the market are difficult; the ‘co-ordination’ problems are significant
  • Risk is a substantial constraint on small farm development, and
  • Good functioning policies should be preserved – there was too much of a tendency to change policy without having found a better one.

    The policy agenda needed to shift towards policies focused on the demand for agricultural produce:

  • The structure of urban areas: metro areas are less the answer than hinterland urbanisation
  • Sectors which generate demand for agriculture
  • Enabling farmer organisation linked to value chains
  • Reduced inequality in land and through taxation

    And, the world needs to allow states to intervene where there is clear market failure, which is especially likely in grain markets, and around development co-ordination issues. Limited protection is still possible within WTO rules for LDCs, so that can also be used. States need to be allowed to enable the reduction of risk faced by small farmers too.

  • Politics, policies and agriculture: the art of the possible in agricultural development

    Achieving pro-poor growth through agriculture: the challenges

    Friday, 25 November 13.00–14.30, at Overseas Development Institute, 111 Westminster Bridge Road, London SE1 7JD

    Politics, policies and agriculture: the art of the possible in agricultural development

    Speaker: Peter Bazeley, founder and Senior Partner of the IDL group until its acquisition by AHG this year, now a freelance consultant and farmer. Extensive experience on agriculture sector reform in Africa and Asia.

    Discussant: Steve Wiggins, ODI Research Fellow

    Chair: Andrew Shepherd, ODI Research Fellow

    Audio (listen to the meeting)
    Peter Bazeley (1)
    Peter Bazeley (2)
    Discussion (1)
    Discussion (2)



    You’ll need Windows Media Player to listen to these clips. You can download the correct version here

    Peter Bazeley (see his presentation) started by noting that failure characterises the context on which to talk about agriculture reform processes in Africa and that a different paradigm is needed on how to reform agriculture in order to have a real impact on growth and livelihoods.

    He identified three important contextual factors for analysing agricultural policy processes. The first of these is that there has been insufficient response in the agriculture sector (in terms of scope and scale) to technological change, institutional reforms (changing the rules of the game) and policy adjustments – he noted that the sector is not achieving what it has to achieve. The second factor is that there are two concurrent processes in the sector with regards to reform: aid effectiveness and modernisation of government agenda in donor countries, running parallel to a focus on policy and institutional reform as a means to achieve change. The third contextual factor is that agriculture, despite the rhetoric, is not doing well in terms of featuring large in PRSPs, or as a beneficiary of improved country-led programming under budgetary support, etc.

    Although policy process was the focus of the talk, he noted that on the substance of policy few important things have happened since structural adjustment and liberalisation the Green Revolution, for example, which was supposed to be something applicable to Africa, has not happened in the continent.

    Making reference to the work of the Imperial at Wye school (work by Dorward, Kydd and Poulton) Peter stressed the importance of the concept of development coordination. He noted it is not about multi-stakeholder coordination – between donors or coordinating projects or programmes across development partners and governments but about balancing and sequencing technical, market, institutional and policy fixes, recognising the multiple factors at play and the interlocking of local, national and international factors.

    On the processes of agriculture policy reform, Peter remarked that we are still largely talking about Sector Wide Approaches (SWAps), despite what many have concluded about their poor performance in agriculture. He argued that the agriculture sector (as well as in other sectors) is still equated to a single (or more, in some countries) organisational structure (Ministry), despite the fact that required reform processes stretch well beyond those structures. The (bold) assumptions underlying the SWAp approach are that the Ministry of Agriculture has the mandate as far as agricultural sector reform is concerned, that sectoral reform processes are to be delegated to the sector technocrats and that this it puts boundaries around scope, scale and capacity. The fundamental problem, Peter noted, is that the debate and experiences have turned these approaches and instruments (such as SWAps) into ends in themselves the complexities of the mechanisms of putting them in practice and the long time horizons required to achieve change have distracted attention from the substance of reform (the actual objectives of reform). The targets used by government and the development community are typically much shorter-term and they do little to address longer-term reform processes.

    Peter noted that he did not expect to be talking about SWAps in the middle of this decade, but that in Africa, both governments and donors are in practice saying that this is the way they want to go forward. SWAps in agriculture have not worked. Despite the years of intense activity and investments around SWAps, farmers have not yet seen tangible benefits from them. Sectoral programmes have tended to work better in other sectors, such as Health and Education. But in the agriculture sector, the approach is harder to apply ,not least because of the centrality, importance and size of the private sector, with which SWAps have failed to engage. He added that agricultural SWAps have largely failed to capture non-agricultural determinants of agriculture productivity and growth. This has led to enormous impatience and to the (probably wrong) conclusion that the problem was with the instrument’s design which led to multiple reorientations and re-starts, perpetuating the focus around process rather than substance.

    Peter Bazeley argued that the determinants of agricultural livelihoods and growth often lie outside a ministry of agriculture’s scope of activity. He illustrated this by providing examples of what participatory poverty assessments (and similar exercises) identified as the determinants of agriculture productivity and growth, in three countries (Malawi, Mozambique and Uganda). Peter noted that only a few of these (such as production technology and information) fall within the mandate of ministries of agriculture that usually lead on agriculture sector reform. However, other issues such as security, justice, contract enforcement, transaction cost, etc. are key for the sector, but are not about the core business of ministries of agriculture.
    What is needed, Peter suggested, is stronger development coordination, which implies a reconfiguration of large-scale high influence policy actions and investments across multiple spheres of public interest. There have been some attempts (although incomplete) of tackling the issue of cross-sectoral reconfiguration.

    The Ugandan Plan for the Modernisation of Agriculture (PMA) was presented as an attempt, at least at its inception, to get the needed cross-sectoral reconfiguration. The original idea behind the PMA, led by the Ugandan Ministry of Finance (not the Ministry of Agriculture), was to reconfigure the governance framework of the rural sector, superimposed with decentralisation objectives. The reform envisaged through the PMA saw agriculture reform as a matter to be tackled by a range of different policy actors, beyond the Ministry of Agriculture alone, filling the gaps between sectoral interventions. But practice proved very different. The PMA ended up largely being absorbed into the Ministry of Agriculture which resisted reform through vehicles not led by the Ministry itself. Earlier innovative attempts both to fund at the district level as well as to constitute a non-sectoral policy and investment forum to deal with cross-cutting issues, backed by basket funding from donors, ended up being watered down.
    The “Enabling Environment for Business with a Particular Emphasis on Agriculture” experience in Zambia could, to some extent, be seen as an example where some innovative reform processes were tried. There the focus was directed towards building capacity (empowering) of the private sector and civil society to demand a better supply of policies in the sector. There was an effort to create new spaces for policy contestation from independent stakeholders.

    In Kenya, the Strategy for Revitalizing Agriculture (SRA) poses interesting challenges on how to achieve supra-ministerial coordination. But the process is still too new to comment on achievements.

    An interesting example from Kenya comes though from the justice, law and order sector. The Governance, Justice, Law and Order Sector (GJLOS) programme emphasises innovative mechanisms of cross-sectoral coordination, and a strong move towards an effective sector-wide perspective. This provides example on how sector-specific issues are determined by other sectors’ problems/issues overcapacity of prisons, for example, is related to the capacity of the judiciary, which in turn is related to performance in public prosecution and in policing all of which are under different ministries and agencies of government. GJLOS thus constitutes a governance framework which could be a source of inspiration for the agriculture sector. For example, Thematic Groups have been created which advise cabinet level committees on how the government should allocate resources. The Medium Term Expenditure Framework (MTEF) is central to resource allocation decisions, on the basis of the thematic group analysis and proposals.

    Peter argued how important the MTEF seems to be (or could be), and how agricultural sector specialists have ignored and not engaged with the process. He believes that the MTEF, as a supra-ministerial cross-government policy statement of medium-term priorities and accountable actions, could play a major role in determining supra-ministerial cross-sectoral strategies.

    Peter Bazeley concluded his presentation by offering a few points for discussion:

  • Is it not that what is lacking in the sector is the ability and capacity (skills and competence) to balance, sequence and reconfigure policies and resources across government organisational structures?
  • Do the sectoral institutions (in the sector) have the necessary cross-sectoral influence to achieve the kind of change needed?
  • What should be done about the sector’s suboptimal performance in engaging with contemporary policy and financing instruments (such as PRSPs, MTEF and so on),
  • How much marginal capacity do line ministries typically have to engage in or manage substantive programmes (of reform) beyond day-to-day business?
  • Is there not validity in conceding that the transaction costs of change should be covered if necessary even through ‘parallel institutions’, supra-governmental agencies, temporary units, etc. …?
  • And, finally, a plea the need for the vision and strategy for the sector to outlive relatively short political and donor cycle, and to accept that policy outcomes need to be negotiated in strongly politicised environment.
  • Steve Wiggins, opening the discussion, started by agreeing that there are few new ideas since the times of structural adjustment and liberalisation. He pointed out, however, despite what some might think there is not agreement on the policy substance and the challenge is not just about understanding the policy process. Steve stressed that agricultural technocrats are nowhere near knowing (and agreeing on) what they want to do. If this is the case, Steve argued, then trying to input ill-formed ideas on the substance into a reform processes might not be very useful it will create a very difficult policy debate.
    The following propositions were presented:

  • In a context of market liberalisation there is a widespread agreement that the role of government is to correct market failures. However, the problem seems to be the lack of agreement on the extent of the failures which would justify government intervention. Steve offered a few examples illustrating this difficulty. How prevalent, for example, is monopoly power in African supply chains? What’s the extent of market failure with regards to information and transaction costs is it not a problem of government failure by gross intervention in markets that would otherwise work?
  • The difficult issues are the institutional issues. As noted by Dani Rodrik, institutional change is the most difficult challenge of development. But in practice, institutional change is often marginalised in favour of more direct actions while the difficult issues get pushed aside.
  • Need to reduce level of uncertainly about the objectives and the means to get there. What may be needed is bold political sense of where the sector is going.
  • Much of the current research on African agricultural development might be using the wrong strategies when dealing with complex systems the best way of getting answers might be through learning from current experiences need to look at successful innovations being made rather then working from the problems.

    Several questions and comments were raised in subsequent discussion:

  • How to manage multi-sectoral planning? Why dismiss the history of experiences with planning? Wouldn’t the creation of cross-cutting sectoral units actually amplify the coordination problems in African governments?
  • The centrality of the MTEF was questioned. Focusing on MTEFs means focusing on public expenditure rather than other important issues such as the institutional issues.
  • What happens to the district level? Not enough attention has been devoted to this important level.
  • Concerns about the difficulty of engaging the private sector in reform processes were expressed. How to coordinate with the millions of private sector operators in the agriculture sector?
  • How to make the difficult link between intention and implementation? Very short term political considerations often determine implementation, how to build these in?
  • Agreement that one of the biggest problems in the sector is the absence of a unified policy message for the sector.
  • It was suggested that part of the analysis about the policy process concerns the debate about the substance (the message).
  • It was noted that the experience of Mozambique shows that the MTEF might not be the answer to cross-sectoral coordination. In Mozambique the instrument was produced mainly by foreign advisors at the Ministry of Finance level and had limited links with the provincial and district levels or indeed the State budget. Engagement of sectoral ministries was usually very poor and constrained by their limited capacity to produce consistent medium-term expenditure plans in sectors with multiple uncoordinated sources of funding.

    Although noting the potential of instruments such as the MTEF, Peter Bazeley concluded that at the moment we do not seem to have the tools (or institutions) to address the important challenge in the agriculture sector, in particular the need for more robust coordination and sequencing of policies and public investment across sectors.

    On a positive note, the chair stressed the relevance of the points raised in the presentation and discussion for the work the Future Agricultures consortium is developing on agricultural policy processes and pro-poor growth. In particular, Andrew Shepherd emphasised the need to re-think about the engagement the agricultural sector in macro policy processes such as SWAPs, PRSs, MTEF and state budgets, and analyse experiences with cross-sectoral coordination including the potential, for example, sector working groups in agriculture and rural development. It was also highlighted the need for policy making to go beyond an expenditure focus of public policies and consider other fundamental issues such as those related to creating the right institutions and an enabling environment for private sector development.

  • What priorities for improved agricultural technology?

    Achieving pro-poor growth through agriculture: the challenges

    Friday, 11 November 13.00–14.30, at Overseas Development Institute, 111 Westminster Bridge Road, London SE1 7JD

    What priorities for improved agricultural technology?

     

    Speakers: Michael Lipton, Sussex University and Anita Ingevall, ILEIA Centre for Information on Low External Input and Sustainable Agriculture.

    Chair: Robert Tripp, ODI Research Fellow

    This meeting was the third of a series of six arranged by the Future Agricultures Consortium, a group comprising researchers at the Institute of Development Studies, Sussex, Imperial College and ODI. The Consortium has been funded by DFID to stimulate debate and generate policy options for agricultural growth.

    Audio (listen to the meeting)

    Michael Lipton (part 1)
    Michael Lipton (part 2)
    Anita Ingevall
    Discussion (part 1)
    Discussion (part 2)
     
    You’ll need Windows Media Player to listen to these clips. You can download the correct version here  

    Michael Lipton (click here for presentation) started by stating the basic problem not as population growth outstripping production, but of the ability of the poor to gain employment and to afford to buy food. Food production on small farms is critical to this for the large numbers of poor people who live in rural areas and are either deficit food producers or landless labourers. Yield growth must play a key role here: the workforce is increasing by 2% per annum, demand for labour must also grow (and so must its productivity). This is important not only for immediate agriculture employment and food access for the poor, it is also a critical starting point for non-agricultural economic and employment growth. Yield growth is important to agricultural employment and productivity growth as opportunities for expanding areas are limited and expansion of agriculture tends to be onto marginal land, leading to land degradation and unsustainable production.

    Returns to agricultural research continue to be high, but since the mid 1980s yield growth has slowed as research has switched its emphasis in green revolution areas from yield growth to yield protection (against pests, water problems, etc), in international centres from plant productivity to other issues such as natural resource management and gender issues in agriculture, and from public to private funded research (with the latter lacking incentives to address the concerns of poor farmers).

    Small farms continue to be important, however, as a major source of employment. Indeed, the proportion of the agricultural work force and land on small farms (defined as less than 5, 2 or 1 ha) has increased since 1965 in most poor countries.
    A number of issues were picked out for further attention.

    First, studies have shown that ‘low potential’ areas now offer the potential for higher returns to research investment than high potential areas, but these tend to be by-passed by private research. Transgenic innovations offer the potential for raising plants that are better able to resist moisture stress.

    Second, increasing global and national water shortages will reduce water available for the production of (low value) staples, as only higher value crops will justify the cost of water. This will result in increasingly ‘anti-poor’ water distribution. Science needs to address this, not only through plant genetic development but also through improved hydraulic systems (there have been no dramatic advances in irrigation systems in modern history).

    Third, crop nutrition enhancement (bio-fortification) presents major opportunities for benefiting the poor (for example through increasing vitamin and mineral content of staple crops at little or no extra cost to producers and consumers). This is an area where transgenics have the potential to deliver major benefits quickly. It is also an issue with potential for greater public led partnerships offering incentives to private research suppliers.

    Public/ private research partnerships also need to be given much greater attention.

    Low external input agriculture (LEIA) as widely practiced (but not promoted) is unfortunately often a form of resource mining (where it is associated with higher outputs) or drives people onto marginal lands (where it is associated with low outputs). Either way it can be a major cause of land degradation. Major LEIA successes include IPM (integrated pest management). However basic input/output relations limit its potential to raise yields in many circumstances. Intensification using external inputs must, however, be sensitive to natural resource management issues.

    Anita Ingevall (click here for presentation) Anita Ingevall began by welcoming the attention being given to this issue and stating that she agreed with much of Michael’s analysis but not with his conclusions. Food production has generally kept pace with population increases but there are now major challenges of sustainability in both high and low potential areas. These are illustrated by the loss of 75% of crop genetic diversity in the last century, a 5% per annum loss in livestock breeds, and land degradation occurring on 50% of cropped land, with soil loss 13 to 18% faster than soil development.

    Agriculture faces major challenges ecologically (for example soil mining, salinisation of irrigated lands, the changes discussed above), economically (with increasing input prices and falling produce prices) and socially (with ageing and declining numbers of people trapped in farming in the north, and rural poverty in the South).
    Food production will be a long term problem and this needs intensification – but it must be ecologically, economically and socially sustainable.

    ILEIA was founded around 20 years ago initially to address concerns with the sustainability of green revolution technologies. It has investigated a wide range of options – such as indigenous, organic and permaculture technologies, working mainly with committed practitioners concerned to optimise local resource use. There have been some major successes (for example the organic movement in the North, a variety of smaller success in the South) but these have tended to be scattered and not coherent. The emphasis is on Low External Input Sustainable Agriculture (LEISA). This involves working within natural constraints, adapting to specific sites, feeding soils and recycling in many ways, emphasising micro-climate management, synergy and complementarity, and minimal fossil fuel use.

    ILEIA has found that LEISA is feasible and viable, that small farms are more productive than larger farms, and that small farmers are willing to invest – but they need support. Support is needed to enhance their secure access to and control of resources (especially land). Institutions are needed to defend their rights. They also need access to information on strategies and specific technologies. Wider policy support is also crucial. Finally, development involves change on a number of local and wider fronts, and farmers need support in coping with and managing transitions.

    Discussion:
    A variety of questions were raised in discussion.

    Harnessing private sector research: how can this be done more effectively, and are there examples of private sector research in LEISA?

    Michael Lipton suggested that more effective harnessing of private sector research required very careful and precise contracts specifying required outputs – and that these needed to be achievable to provide private sector research organizations with profit incentives – but that other incentives to private sector investment can also be important (such as their need to attract top quality researchers and allow them some flexibility to work on interesting and socially important issues). He suggested that organic farming might be a LEISA area which private sector research might have a role. Anita Ingevall stressed the difficulties that common property rights posed for private research investment.

    What are the implications of long term challenges of climate change and fossil fuel depletion?

    Anita Ingevall pointed out the very inefficient use of fossil fuels in many intensive production systems, and also in food distribution systems. There is a need to adapt to fossil fuel shortages by sourcing local produce. Michael Lipton commented that high energy and transport costs will hit low value products hardest (although transport costs have been falling). This question also meant that in some circumstances investments in roads in Africa needs to be questioned – although there is a serious need for better roads in Africa in some areas it is important to ask what supply and demand the roads will serve.
    What should be done about large areas of marginal land being cropped unsustainably (for example in some areas of Southern Africa)?

    Michael Lipton commented that there is a need to intensify with better water control and use of inorganic fertilizer where it can be done in sustainable ways with economic benefit – subsidies to intensification in other circumstances are damaging. In some areas of West Africa there are very low returns to fertilizer without higher levels of organic matter in the soil – there is then a need to identify farmer incentives for undertaking costly investments in applying organic matter to the soil – this needs better farmer access to water control, crop germplasm and inorganic fertilizers so that organic matter investments can yield returns to farmers.

    Can LEISA benefit from transgenic technologies (for example Bt maize has encouraged conservation tillage and ox-ploughing with reduced tractor ploughing in parts of KwaZulu-Natal in South Africa)?

    Anita Ingevall responded by noting that some LEIA technologies, such as conservation tillage, have been part of mainstream commercial agriculture – but that these could be pursued without GM. Michael Lipton argued that there was potential for strong complementarity between GM techniques and LEISA – as argued, for example, by Professor Swaminathan, a leading figure in the Asian green revolution.

    Is it practical for international research centres to concentrate more on generic yield enhancement issues and to leave more locally specific NRM management and social issues to national research systems when national research systems are often weak?

    Michael Lipton agreed that NARS are often weak, because African governments are so stretched as regards public expenditure constraints – and this means that donor investments in this area often allow reductions in governments’ own expenditure commitments. There are also very substantial incentive and system problems that prevent highly able and committed staff in NARS from being effective. These systemic problems need to be addressed – capacity building by itself is not enough. Nevertheless there are some very effective NARS in Africa (for example in Kenya)

    Can small farmers make more use of the stock of technologies that have already been developed for large, corporate farming?
    Both speakers agreed that although there is some potential for this there are also fundamental differences in technology needs between small and large farms, and this limits the extent to which ‘on the shelf’ technologies for large farms can be adapted to the benefit of small farms. A big advantage of seed and fertilizer technologies is that they are generally divisible (apart from transaction costs of accessing them): this is not the case with many other (for example machinery) technologies.

    Can the high costs of obtaining expert knowledge on LEISA be reduced?

    The speakers agreed that this is a major challenge. Anita reported that much more information is now available than it was – but it can be difficult to track down and apply.

    Can international research centres deliver demand driven research to small farmers or are they too remote, and how can the more locally specific science demands for LEISA be met?

    Michael Lipton suggested that paradoxically the international research system had been more effective in promoting participatory research approaches than national and local research systems. Anita Ingevall questioned this. She noted that the development of locally specific technologies required the development of wider strategic solutions and principles.
    How quickly could transgenics science come up with solutions to the water challenges posed by Michael?

    Michael Lipton agreed that this is a major challenge – very substantial resources will be needed over a long period. He suggested as a very rough estimate that a period of 15 years or so could deliver substantial progress if the whole CG system budget (£300 million per year) were devoted to it. Anita Ingevall suggested that this will never happen, the challenge is too great: plants cannot be pushed to increase their output on two major fronts (moisture stress resistance and high yields). Michael Lipton commented that the long history of plant breeding suggested that net gains in plant performance are possible.

    Conclusion
    The chair noted the agreement between the speakers on the major challenges to agriculture and poverty reduction and the importance of technology to this, agreement on some responses but differences over others. He thanked the speakers for their informative and stimulating presentations and discussion.

    Agriculture and the rural non-farm sector: rivals or complements?

    Achieving pro-poor growth through agriculture: the challenges

    Friday, 4 November 13.00–14.30, at Overseas Development Institute, 111 Westminster Bridge Road, London SE1 7JD

    Agriculture and the rural non-farm sector: rivals or complements?

    Speakers: Deborah Bryceson, Leiden and Peter Hazell, Imperial College

    The meeting was chaired by Steve Wiggins (ODI)

    This meeting was the second of a series of six arranged by the Future Agricultures Consortium, a group comprising researchers at the Institute of Development Studies, Sussex, Imperial College and ODI. The Consortium has been funded by DFID to stimulate debate and generate policy options for agricultural growth.

    Audio (listen to the meeting)

    Deborah Bryceson (part 1)
    Deborah Bryceson (part 2)
    Peter Hazell (part 1)
    Peter hazell (part 2)
    Discussion (part 1)
    Discussion (part 2)

    You’ll need Windows Media Player to listen to these clips. You can download the correct version here

    Peter Hazell outlined the key characteristics of the rural non-farm economy (RNFE). Typically the sector generates around 35-40% of rural incomes and occupies about 25% of labour time: these shares are higher for the rural poor who depend disproportionately on the RNFE for their livelihoods. The sector consists of heterogeneous activities; typically produced on a small scale, tending to agglomerate in rural market centres.

    Most of what is produced is non-tradable, being consumed in local markets. This means the sector depends on the growth of rural activities that produce tradables of which agriculture is usually the main example. Given such growth, multipliers stimulate the RNFE, partly from linkages in production inputs, processing, etc. but above all from spending of additional (agricultural) incomes in consumption linkages. The multipliers can be considerable: estimates for Asia run in the range of 1.6 to 1.9, for Latin America 1.3 to 1.5, and for Africa 1.3 to 1.5.

    Globalisation and market liberalisation can create opportunities: the output of some rural activities become tradable a prime example being tourism in remote rural areas of outstanding natural beauty. On the other hand, competition from imports can decimate rural manufacturing including craft production.

    The RNFE is affected by the investments of large private firms, NGO programmes and government policies. Policy for the sector, however, tends to be uncoordinated: usually there is no single government ministry or agency that has overview of the RNFE. The appropriate role for government is that of

  • creating an enabling environment institutions and policies, provision of physical infrastructure and human capital, and stimulating rural financial systems, where there is much scope for putting rural savings to work;
  • ensuring the poor have access to opportunities, and that there is buffering from market shocks; and
  • sustaining the environment.
    Principles for public intervention include:
  • Assessing the regional context, where the key point is to foster engines or drivers of growth, that is activities capable of producing tradable surpluses. In remote rural areas finding these may be difficult;
  • Analysing supply chains, with tools as simple as SWOT, to identify bottlenecks; and,
  • Building flexible institutional coalitions of government, private and NGO agencies to make interventions, rather than creating new public bureaucracies that may stifle private initiatives.
  • Deborah Bryceson, (click here for presentation) , noting her approach to be that of a geographer and sociologist, stressed the changing work patterns seen in rural areas, and associated cultural changes. Most of what follows comes from observing African cases.

    The 1980s saw price movements against traditional smallholder export crops. As structural adjustment programmes were introduced, households diversified into a wider range of activities. This not only produced a stratification of peasant households, but also women and youth became significant earners of cash incomes. As markets were progressively liberalised in the 1990s, export crops came to be seen as an old man’s occupation, while women and youth moved into diversified activities in the RNFE although the patterns that emerged were highly varied by location. Urbanisation, above all the growth of secondary towns, proved a major stimulus.

    In Tanzania the strong growth of opportunities in tourism, urban areas, and in gold mining by the end of 2003 formal mining was earning more than US$600M in forex, three times the value of traditional export crops accelerated de-peasantisation.

    In Malawi, the rural areas were hit by the decline in remittances from migrant labour. With low rates of urbanisation and little to invest in intensified farming, a process of agricultural involution took place. The results seen include rampant poverty, with many forced to resort to casual (‘ganyu’) labour, recurrent famines, peasants dispossessed of land, and as if it this were not bad enough having to cope with HIV/AIDS as well.

    For households, considerations of agriculture or the non-farm economy is not an issue: they seek whatever opportunities that can be had. But in the process we see loss of coherence of households. In Tanzania, new opportunities offer more flexibility, while in Malawi we see desperation. Agricultural specialists need to recognise the emerging patterns, with the associated changes in lifestyles and attitudes.

    In conclusion:

  • Old models of rural activity, with smallholder farming at the core, are disintegrating;
  • Producing traditional agricultural commodities for export is a lost cause unless there is major reform to address the imbalance between producer subsidies received by farmers in developed countries as opposed to farmers without subsidies in developing countries;
  • Linkages between farming and the RNFE are affected by changes in household relations for farming households there is a crisis in access to agricultural inputs;
  • Rural households will continue, however, to try as far as possible to produce the bulk of their staple foods; and,
  • A national policy challenge is to find ways to facilitate commercial food production.

    The following issues arose in discussion:

    The role of remittances: a source of investment and consumption, as well as a way to offset risks in rural activities, noted Peter Hazell.

    Rainfall variations: Deborah Bryceson agreed these had a strong effect on rural economies, as did movements in commodity prices.
    The basis for public interventions: the government role needs to be restricted to correcting market failures. Peter Hazell agreed: government had a poor record of co-ordination, coalitions of common interest that could be led by private firms or NGOs were a better way to get the public goods and institutions provided.

    The salience of urbanisation and its potential to transform rural economies. Deborah Bryceson noted how rural areas can be urbanised: energy, electricity above all, is key all manner of new activities can be undertaken once power supplies are to hand. Scope exists for active policy on urbanisation, in zoning, for example.

    Estimates of multipliers: critiques of quantitative models, including those for the Muda Valley in Malaysia, pointed out that they ignored the distribution of benefits across households and between areas, and that they took no account of environmental impacts. Peter Hazell replied that the study of Muda took place in the early 1970s, when Malaysia was still an agrarian country, when getting growth was paramount. That capital flowed out from the Valley may have been true, but the multipliers were both large and contained within Malaysia for the overall benefit of national development.

    Distribution of benefits matters, insisted one participant. The quantitative models tell us only so much of the story: we need to know more of the dynamics in particular locations; we need to learn from specific cases of success.

    Transport: Peter Hazell pointed out that the poorer the physical infrastructure the weaker the linkages seen are.
    Disaster relief monies have the potential to produce dramatic impacts on rural economies, but how sustainable are such impacts? Deborah Bryceson replied that mining had similar effects of creating a sudden large injection of funds into the rural economy.

    Where should investment in rural areas go? And if we speak of engines of growth, should this be agriculture? Peter Hazell noted that agriculture was often the only option, especially in Africa South of the Sahara. Despite this there had been little investment in farming by government or donors. In contrast, in Vietnam, public investment in agriculture had produced, within a decade, large increases in exports of crops such as coffee.

    Deborah Bryceson concurred that governments had done too little on behalf of agriculture,. Indeed structural adjustment policies had betrayed the green revolution in Africa. Fertiliser subsidies, targeted to deserving farmers, were a case in point: in Malawi the loss of subsidies on fertiliser was one of the most keenly felt grievances in rural areas. Policy, she added, cannot be laissez-faire: government has to have a vision, and it needs to recognise de-agrarianisation.

     

  • Effective rural institutions: the missing link in market-based agricultural development?

    Achieving pro-poor growth through agriculture: the challenges

    Friday, 28 October 13.00–14.30, at Overseas Development Institute, 111 Westminster Bridge Road, London SE1 7JD

    Effective rural institutions: the missing link in market-based agricultural development?
    Why has market liberalisation often not resulted in increased rates of agricultural growth? A leading hypothesis sees failures in output and factor markets as the main cause, and institutional innovation as the remedy. If so, what kinds of institutional innovations are needed, and how can they be promoted?

     

    Speakers: Jonathan Kydd, Imperial College and John Harriss, Director, DESTIN. London School of Economics.

    The meeting was chaired by Steve Wiggins (ODI)

     

    Meeting Report

    This meeting was the first of a series of six arranged by the Future Agricultures Consortium, a group comprising researchers at the Institute of Development Studies, Sussex, Imperial College and ODI. The Consortium has been funded by DFID to stimulate debate and generate policy options for agricultural growth.

    Audio (listen to the meeting)

    Jonathan Kydd (part 1)
    Jonathan Kydd (part 2)
    John Harriss (part 1)
    John Harriss (part 2)
    Discussion (part 1)
    Discussion (part 2)

    You’ll need Windows Media Player to listen to these clips. You can download the correct version here

    Jonathan Kydd (click here for presentation) started by defining institutions as the ‘rules of the game’, that is those underlying conventions and norms that make economic interchange more predictable. The common use of the term ‘institution’ to refer to an organisation is excluded, although every organisation has a set of rules of working practices that in themselves are institutional. He went on to outline some of the key concepts in institutional economics above all those of transactions costs. These are the costs of exchange: collection of information prior to the deal, negotiating with other parties to the exchange, and monitoring the subsequent exchanges.

    Neo-classical economics assumes these costs away: markets are expected to operate with no friction at all. In reality, for some exchanges and in particular circumstances, transactions costs can be so high that exchanges do not take place, despite the clear economic opportunity for both parties to gain.

    How do these ideas help us understand the issues in African agricultural development? In the 1970s and 1980s, many African countries, and especially those of Eastern & Southern Africa, created large parastatal enterprises, with monopoly powers, to manage the supply chain for agriculture. They typically provided inputs of seed and fertiliser to farmers, usually on credit, and then guaranteed to buy up whatever marketed surplus farmers would offer after the harvest. Transactions costs were low, but only since the state was prepared to subsidise operations and absorb losses. Although the agricultural parastatals had several successes in stimulating smallholder production of both food and cash crops, they proved unsustainable. Costs were high, inefficiencies were rife. Hence from the mid-1980s most of them were either closed or scaled down.

    The new model for agricultural development was based on liberalised markets where the private sector was expected to provide inputs, supply credit and to buy up produce and to do so more efficiently than the old public sector monopolies. The public sector role has been reduced to that of providing ‘consensus public goods’ for example, roads, some agricultural research and extension. The institutional agenda has been one-dimensional, with much interest in property rights, but other institutions being more or less ignored.

    The liberalised model has functioned where certain conditions apply: dense physical infrastructure, and a growing and diversified agriculture. Bangladesh would be a good example. But other cases, and in much of Africa where these conditions do not apply, the result has been the green revolutions that the parastatals had fostered have stalled. Faced by high transactions costs largely those of information by which suppliers and traders come to understand the economic potential and moral character of farmers, and by which farmers learn of the possibilities of inputs and markets private investors have been deterred and have turned their back on agricultural markets.

    What are the implications of these observations? Jonathan Kydd and his colleagues argue that agricultural development should be seen as consisting of three stages of public action, thus:
    1. Establish the basic public goods that allow farmers to invest and produce roads, agricultural research and extension services, in areas with potential, irrigation schemes, and in some cases land tenure reform;
    2. Kick-start the markets by active state intervention in the provision of farm inputs, and, above all, seasonal finance for agriculture;
    3. Once a certain level of production has been reached, withdraw from the markets, leaving the field to the private sector.
    The case of India provides support for this model. Analysis of data carried out in collaboration with IFPRI shows varying returns to different investments through time. In the 1960s the highest returns to public investment were in roads and irrigation; and subsequently in the 1970s by spending on fertiliser subsidies and rural credit provision investments that are now anathema to those recommending liberalisation. By the 1990s the returns to inputs and finance had declined. Only in the later decades has education paid off in agricultural productivity.

    The process of institutional development, following Fafchamps, is likely to see agricultural supply chains change from those in which face-to-face, intensive and personal exchanges between farmers and traders dominate; to those in which relations are defined as much by (organisational) hierarchies as by markets, and in which reputation is critical.
    Jumping stages too early and omitting stages one and two is likely to condemn a country to a low-level equilibrium trap. Otherwise profitable opportunities for agricultural development go begging since the transactions costs at early stages of development are just too high to allow sufficient returns to be made.

    John Harriss (click here for presentation) sketched out the current dilemmas of agricultural development in India, starting by taking two examples of recent investments in farming. A private investor from the telecommunications sector, with funds from an merchant bank, tried to set up a schemes for export agriculture but found it difficult to ship produce promptly. Poor infrastructure and bureaucratic requirements at the border were blamed. On the public side, the World Bank has recently approved a loan to encourage diversified production in Uttar Pradesh, with a comprehensive package that includes innovations in the supply chain for more effective marketing.

    Will such schemes benefit small and marginal farmers, or will they be biased towards larger farmers? When new lines of production for higher value markets have ‘credence characteristics’ for example, the way in which items have been produced, or pesticide applications and residues that cannot readily be checked by inspecting the produce, larger units have economies in providing such assurance. Farmer associations potentially allow smaller farms to interact with major players in supply chains, but the experience has been that they are typically captured by the larger farmers.

     

    For staples production, in parts of India, the green revolution is running out of steam. Environmental problems of increasing pesticide resistance, and the depletion of aquifers have emerged. Prices have become more volatile in a liberalised setting. And input prices have risen more than those for output, squeezing margins. Moreover, liberalisation in the 1990s in India has meant that formal finance is less available for small farmers, pushing them towards informal lenders. The overall picture is gloomy, dramatically illustrated by media reports of suicides by farmers unable to pay off their debts.

    Small and marginal farmers the majority of Indian farms are increasingly marginal by any definition are not out of the market: the problem they face is that they are deeply engaged in markets, but on adverse terms.

    Do these changes indicate that only large-scale, capitalised farming can make progress? And if so, what is the fate of the small and marginal farmers? Or does India need a new round of agrarian reform, with the state returning to a more active role to ensure that the small and marginal farmers have access to finance, inputs and technical advice?

    Discussion saw the following points being raised:
    What is the nature of the state and its policies that would be able to see through stages one and two of the model presented? In the case of India there were important contextual features to the start of the green revolution, including the legacy of long-term support to Indian agricultural research from Ford and Rockefeller, and large civil service with considerable capacity.
    Jonathan Kydd admitted that to some extent one must await a certain level of state capacity before renewed agricultural development would be possible. Regional trading blocks with harmonised agricultural policy would, however, allow conditions to be created for the smaller states where capacity is low.

    Is there scope for collective action by smaller farmers? John Harriss noted that larger farmers can dominate and lock small and marginal farmers in to relations where they are condemned to poverty.

    Was it possible to replicate the experience of Bangladesh where energetic promotion by micro-finance by NGOs had taken place? Both speakers noted that micro-finance tends to be provided for shorter term finance rather than farm input loans. The problem becomes acute where the farming system is based around a single, long season a year where loans are likely to be outstanding for six or more months. Many countries in Africa, for example, have only one cropping season.
    How feasible is it for states to withdraw from agricultural markets in stage three? Jonathan Kydd notes that in some cases the third stage sees an incomplete liberalisation: look, for example, at the European Common Agricultural Policy, or at the Republic of Korea, where the third stage has seen heavy state support to farmers. India is currently facing great difficulty in cutting back some forms of support to farmers.

    How feasible is agricultural development, and smallholder agricultural development? Both speakers noted that progress was possible in unpromising circumstances. For example, between 1985 and 1993, Malawi had seen a genuine green revolution in the production of maize. In Bihar dairy co-operatives were had succeeded, despite the frequent failure of such associations in other sectors.

    The chair summarised the meeting in three propositions:
    1. Institutions are clearly important to agricultural development;
    2. Institutions could be promoted by an active state or through private initiative deciding the more appropriate route in particular cases is a key question; and,
    3. Private initiatives tend to be understated in debates on institutions, and cases of success in private institutional innovations are under-reported and under-appreciated. A key challenge is to document more of such cases, and to understand the factors that make for success.

    Communities, Commodities and Crazy Ideas: Changing Livestock Policies in Africa

    In the late 1990s a review of aid-assisted livestock projects included an assessment of sustained impact on poorer producers (Ashley et al. 1998). The review looked back over 35 years and analysed documents from more than 800 livestock projects funded by major donors, including the Department foInternational Development (UK), the World Bank, the US Agency for International Development, the European Commission, DANIDA, theNetherlands Development Cooperation and the Swiss Development Cooperation.

    The majority of these projects were based on a technical transfer paradigmin which constraints facing poor livestock keepers were to be addressed by the development anduptake of technologies, including new methods to control animal diseases, improve livestock breedsor raise production through a variety of other means. However, the lack of sustained impact on the poowas dramatic. In many cases, technologies were developed which livestock keepers either did not want or could not access due to weak delivery systems. In other cases, the benefits of new technologies were captured by wealthier producers.

    Partly in response to these problems, a second broa category of livestock projects evolved which aimed to strengthen the capacity of organisations to develop and deliver novel technologies and services to the poor. These projects focused on government organisations (veterinary and extension services, research centres) and aimed to promote more clientfocused and decentralised approaches. A key project activity was training middle-level managers, researchers and field-level technicians. Again, the sustained benefit of these “organisational projects” was limited.

    New skills did not change the way organisations behaved, as the overriding institutional frameworks rarely provided incentives for addressing the specific needs of the poor. Despite this rather gloomy picture a few projects did demonstrate substantial impact. These included new approaches to primary animal health care using privatised community-based animal health workers (CAHWs). Working in marginalised arid and semiarid areas of East Africa, local problem analysis wit communities led to the selection and training of CAHWs in areas where few veterinarians were willing to work. However, even these projects faced problems at a policy and institutional level – veterinary policies and legislation did not support CAHWs and were often vague or not implemented.

    This article describes how workers at the Africa Union/InterAfrican Bureau for Animal Resources (AU/IBAR) addressed policy constraints toCAHWservices in theHorn and East Africa. The AU/IBAR team developed and applied a range of lobbying, advocacy, networking and learning methods within an overall strategy which recognised the overtly political nature of the policy process. Over time, the teamalso targeted global animal health standard setting bodies and began to apply their experience of policy process to a broader range of livestock policies.

    IDS Bulletin: New Directions for African Agriculture

    IDS Bulletin
    Vol. 36 No. 2, 2005

    Edited by Ian Scoones, Aaron deGrassi, Stephen Devereux and Lawrence Haddad

    Both this year’s UN Millennium Report and The Commission for Africa Report highlight the lack of progress in achieving the Millennium Development Goals (MDGs) in sub-Saharan Africa. What role should agriculture have in this challenge? Most of Africa’s poor are rural, and most rely largely on agriculture for their livelihoods. Inevitably, “getting agriculture moving” must be part of the solution to the seemingly intractable problem of African poverty. While the standard storyline about African agriculture is not positive, there have been some notable achievements in the past decade. Are these successes exceptional and limited to particular settings and times, or are they replicable across wider areas, benefiting larger numbers of people?

    IDSdirectionsThis IDS Bulletin draws together contributions from a diverse range of researchers and development practitioners working in Africa, with the common goal of exploring why agriculture is contributing to poverty reduction and livelihood improvement in some places. This debate comes at a critical time when there is renewed interest in agriculture in Africa and a real commitment to revitalise the sector. How to translate words into reality? How to avoid the recycling of old ideas, and generate new thinking – rooted in African contexts and ground realities – which makes a difference? Central to all solutions are social, cultural and political factors: rather than an expert-driven, technocratic approach, a more politically-sophisticated stance is required with a new emphasis on understanding and influencing processes of innovation, intervention and policy. The aim of this IDS Bulletin is to contribute to this journey.

    Agricultural Markets in West Africa: Frontiers, Agribusiness and Social Differentiation

    {jathumbnail off}{jcomments off}Neoliberal policies have in recent years focused on introducing institutional reform to facilitate and regulate the operation of free markets. It is still assumed that the freemarket is the best mechanism to achieve efficient and equitable growth, alongsidetechnical prescriptions. A growing body of research on the political economy of agribusiness and the ways in which agribusiness and geopolitical interestscapture world commodity markets is largely ignored within mainstream agricultural development literature on Africa. After 20 years of neoliberal reform in Africa, the same old formulas are dogmatically asserted without critical reflection.

    Bates (1981) dealt a telling indictment of the elite basis of state policies in Africa. But his analysis largely focused on abstract models ofmarkets and failed to examine the interventions of the state in agricultural production, which were often based on linkages with agribusiness and aspiring private sector capitalists. The interventions of the state in agriculture served not only to promote patronage but also the development of capitalist agriculture and agribusiness.

    Bates failed to analyse the interests of agribusiness in expanding into developing country markets. This is an important factor, since the open market policies he advocated play into the interests of agribusiness. This article examines how agricultural markets have been shaped by power relations, often at the expense of the rural poor, and how the organisation of frontiers, transport and input supplies affect export crop, food and agribusiness production. The frontier and export crop In looking at state interventions that control producer prices to the detriment of farmers, one ofthe sectors that Bates focused on was cocoa production in Ghana.

    Bates argues that the state sought to appropriate an increasing proportion of the producer price to use in expanding its political patronage. As a result farmers stopped producing cocoa and turned to food production. During the 1980s Côte d’Ivoire was regarded as the economic miracle of Africa, whose open door policies favoured growth. By the 1990s the Ivorian economy entered crisis as world cocoa prices collapsed, and there were structural similarities between this and the earlier crisis in Ghana.

    The existence of excellent research on the interaction between production, market prices, and crisis in Côte d’Ivoire enables us to re-evaluate the earlier crisis in Ghana. Cocoa production throughout the world is patterned on cycles of boom, collapse and movement of cocoa to new frontier areas ofremaining forest land. Cocoa is subject to a ‘forest rent’ (Ruf 1997). New areas of production achieve windfalls from soil conditions, moisture, and lack of weeds and pests, which are reflected in low production costs. As cocoa plantations become old they become less productive, susceptible to pests, and weed populations build up. The cost of labour and inputs increase and profits decline. The cost of rehabilitating cocoa in old producing zones is high.

    Cocoa producers respond by migrating to new areas of forest where production costs are lower.Labour migrates to these new areas since labouring is less arduous and gains better returns. The decline of production in old areas can result in higher world prices.New frontier areas come into production

    Key Challenges for Technology Development and Agricultural Research in Africa

    {jathumbnail off}{jcomments off}Agricultural development is a sine qua non fo improving livelihoods in Africa’s predominantlyrural economies, yet agricultural productivity has hardly improved and African food production percapita continues to decline. This is not because of a lack of planning efforts, but rather because thesehave not been of the scale required to have an impact on such huge problems. Past efforts have also no been sufficiently holistic for advancing comple systems and have not been pursued with thenecessary long-term vision and willingness to take the risks that are inherent in implementinginnovations.

    To break the poverty trap experienced by the majority of African smallholders andpastoralists, these issues must be addressed. Targets for African poverty reduction are not being achieved. Many individual programmes and institutions show good returns to investment in agricultural research and development, but the sum of their collective effort falls far short of making a significant impact at the national level on poverty reduction and food security.2 Examples of innovations that have had significant impact Significant impact comes from significanintellectual and financial input. The two billion people – 30 per cent of the world’s total – that depend on the Haber–Bosch process of synthesisings (million Kshs )

    New Direction for African Agriculture

    {jathumbnail off}{jcomments off}This year’s UNMillennium Report highlights the lack of progress in achieving the Millennium Development Goals (MDGs) in sub-Saharan Africa. The Commission for Africa report (2005) similarly highlights themajor challenges of poverty reduction on the continent.What role should agriculture have in this challenge? Most of Africa’s poor are rural, and most rely largely on agriculture for their livelihoods. Inevitably, “getting agriculture moving” must be part of the solution to the seemingly intractable problem of African poverty.

    The standard storyline about African agriculture is not positive. In most countries, the sector is slow growing or stagnant, held back by negligible yield growth, poor infrastructure, degrading environmental resources, erratic weather, HIV/AIDS and civil conflict. But sweeping, generalised analyses often hide important stories of success. As Toulmin and Guèye (in this IDS Bulletin) highlight for West Africa, there have been some notable achievements in the past decade. This is replicated elsewhere, as Wiggins observes (also in this IDS Bulletin), where supplyled successes – including in hybrid maize, horticulture, dairy, cassava (see also Haggblade and Gabre-Madhin 2004) – have combined with new sources of demand, due to improvements in infrastructure, changing market conditions or the opening up of niche opportunities. Are these successes exceptional and limited to particular settings and times, or are they replicable across wider areas, benefiting larger numbers of people?

    This IDS Bulletin draws together contributions from a diverse range of researchers and development practitioners working in Africa, with the common goal of exploring why agriculture is contributing to poverty reduction and livelihood improvement in some places, but not in many. Identifying ways forward implies moving away from failed past prescriptions, identifying and building on current successes and encouraging new and innovative thinking about future pathways and opportunities. This debate comes at a critical time. As the African Union’s Commissioner for Agriculture and Rural Economy notes in the foreword to this IDS Bulletin, there is renewed interest in agriculture in Africa and a real commitment to revitalise the sector.

    This comes fromnumerous sources – whether frominternational initiatives such as the UNMillenniumProject’s Task Force onHunger (2005) or theCommission for Africa report (2005); from within Africa, such as the African Union and NEPAD’s (New Partnership for Africa’s Development) Comprehensive Africa Agriculture Development Programme(CAADP) (NEPAD 2003), from national governments themselves or from the international donor community (USAID 2004; DFID 2003; World Bank 2002). But how to translate these words into reality? How to avoid the recycling and repackaging of old – and often failed – ideas? How to generate new thinking, rooted in African contexts and ground realities, whichmakes a difference? The aim of this IDS Bulletin is to contribute to this journey.

    The central puzzle is: Why is African agriculture (largely) stagnating? This question is not new. Many have commented on the failures of an African “green revolution”, and many explanations have been suggested. The following sections outline three responses: “technical fixes”, “market and institutional fixes” and “policy fixes”. Each approach reflects a different way of looking at the problem, and each implies different ways forward. The IDS Bulletin draws on insights from across sub-Saharan Africa and is organised as follows. Three scenesetting articles follow this introductory piece. Then there are clusters of articles focusing on “resources and technologies”, “markets and institutions” and“policies and policy processes”.

    Governing Technology Development: Challenges for Agricultural Research in Africa

    There is little doubt that agricultural research is of critical importance to the future of agriculture in Africa. As an investment, it has been shown again and again to deliver high returns, in terms of both financial benefits (Alston et al. 2000; Evenson and Gollin 2003; although, see Morris and Heisey 2003), and broader livelihood impacts (Meinzen-Dick et al. 2004). Yet agricultural research is in crisis on the continent, its capacity decimated by a combination of government neglect and externally imposed policy conditionalities. This has resulted in a significant loss of key personnel and the undermining of locally based, contextually relevant research efforts. Neither the international system through the CGIAR (Consultative Group on International Agricultural Research), nor the private sector has been able to fill the gap.

    In its 2005 report, the Commission for Africa rinjeecognises this challenge, and argues for a US$3bnction of funds for technology-focused capacity bofuilding in Africa. Similarly, the Hunger Taskforcethe Millennium Project argued in 2004 that a science and technology-driven agenda – focused on aigreen revolution package of seeds, fertilisers andrrigation – was the route to meeting theMillennium Development Goals (MDG) targets. The 2004 Inter- Academy Council report also highlighted the challenges of technology development and associated capacity building. Everyone seems to agree that the years of neglect have been disastrous.However, large cash injections and calls for improving “capacity” agre one thing; seeing this through to impacts on theround is another.

    Agricultural Markets in West Africa: Frontiers, Agribusiness and Social Differentiation

    By Kojo Sebastian Amanor

    Neoliberal policies have in recent years focused on introducing institutional reform to facilitate and regulate the operation of free markets. It is still assumed that the freemarket is the best mechanism to achieve efficient and equitable growth, alongside technical prescriptions. A growing body of researchon the political economy of agribusiness and the ways in which agribusiness and geopolitical interests capture world commodity markets is largely ignored within mainstream agricultural development literature on Africa. After 20 years of neoliberal reform in Africa, the same old formulas are dogmatically asserted without critical reflection.

    Agricultural Markets in West Africa: Frontiers, Agribusiness and Social Differentiation

    Neoliberal policies have in recent years focused on introducing institutional reform to facilitate and regulate the operation of free markets. It is still assumed that the freemarket is the best mechanism to achieve efficient and equitable growth, alongsidetechnical prescriptions. A growing body of research on the political economy of agribusiness and the ways in which agribusiness and geopolitical interestscapture world commodity markets is largely ignored within mainstream agricultural development literature on Africa. After 20 years of neoliberal reform in Africa, the same old formulas are dogmatically asserted without critical reflection.

    Key Challenges for Technology Development and Agricultural Research in Africa – 4

    By Monty Jone

    Agricultural development is a sine qua non for improving livelihoods in Africa’s predominantlyrural economies, yet agricultural productivity has hardly improved and African food production percapita continues to decline. This is not because of a lack of planning efforts, but rather because thesehave not been of the scale required to have an impact on such huge problems. Past efforts have also no been sufficiently holistic for advancing comple systems and have not been pursued with thenecessary long-term vision and willingness to take the risks that are inherent in implementinginnovations. To break the poverty trap experienced by the majority of African smallholders andpastoralists, these issues must be addressed.

    Neo-patrimonialism and Policy Processes

    In the 1990s economic liberalisation replaced state support for agriculture across much of Southern Africa. As well as reducing costs, it was assumed that liberalisation would ensure food availability and access to food through positive effects on production and trade incentives and on incomes.However, subsequent experience has not matched this vision: in December 2002, 16 million people in the region (30 per cent of the population) were declared in danger of running out of food.

    Governing Technology Development: Challenges for Agricultural Research in Africa

    There is little doubt that agricultural research is of critical importance to the future of agriculture in Africa. As an investment, it has been shown again afinnd again to deliver high returns, in terms of bothancial benefits (Alston et al. 2000; Evenson and Gaollin 2003; although, seeMorris andHeisey 2003),nd broader livelihood impacts (Meinzen-Dick et al. 2004). Yet agricultural research is in crisis on tche continent, its capacity decimated by aombination of government neglect and externally impoinsed policy conditionalities. This has resulteda significant loss of key personnel and the urndermining of locally based, contextually relevantesearch efforts. Neither the international system through the CGIAR (Consultative Group on International Agricultural Research), nor the private sector has been able to fill the gap.

    Beyond Liberalisation: “Developmental Coordination” Policies for African Smallholder Agriculture

    By Andrew Dorward, Jonathan Kydd and Colin Poulton

    This article argues for a fresh approach to agricultural policy in Africa, to exploit the strengths of both stateled and market-led development approaches pursued over the last 50 years, while avoiding their respective weaknesses and addressing the particular challenges and opportunities facing agricultural development in the early twenty-first century. Following a brief review of agricultural development policy, we describe the coordination problems in agricultural development and suggest an inclusive policy goal of “developmental coordination”.

    Investing in Africa: The Political Economy of Agricultural Growth – 2

    By Adebayo Olukoshi

    IDS Bulletin Vol 36 No 2 June 2005

    If investments are good for growth, then a question which has always exercised the minds of economists and policy-makers historically, is just how to generate, attract, secure and sustain them. This is not a question to which there are easy answers, although there is no shortage of economic models which seek to identify the determinants of growth and propose universally applicable principles.One perspective that has become dominant in policy circles suggests that “secure” property rights constitute the sine qua non for the generation of investments, as well as for increased productivity, income and growth. This perspective, which is currently being applied across developing countries, is, however, contested by another school of thought which argues that evidence on the correlation between the rights regime (or the governance environment) and the direction and pattern of investment flows is very thin indeed. China is one frequently cited example in this connection, but the cases of Nigeria and Angola, two of the most important destinations for foreign investment flows in Africa, have also been cited. Investor behaviour, though, is very often based on subjective sentiments, hunches about possibilities that may exist, and the mentality of the herd, and not so much on a priori calculations about whether or not property rights are “secure”. This article explores these alternative perspectives, examining some elements of the political economy of growth and investment.

    Success Stories from African Agriculture: What are the Key Elements of Success?

    By Steve Wiggins

    IDS Bulletin Vol 36 No 2 June 2005

    Success is not a word often heard when dealing with contemporary issues in agriculture in Sub- Saharan Africa. For 30 years, the overall picture has been one of failure.While other regions of the developing world have seen increases in agricultural production per capita, Sub-Saharan Africa has seen a decline, the index falling from 114 in 1969–1971 to 97 for 2002–04, a 15 per cent fall over 33 years (data from the United Nations Food and Agriculture Organization Statistics (FAOSTAT)). Consequently, Africa has lost much of its share of international trade in agricultural produce, and has seen rising levels of food imports.

    Livelihoods Research Findings and Agriculture-led Growth

    By Godfrey Bahiigwa, Ntengua Mdoe and Frank Ellis

    IDS Bulletin Vol 36 No 2 June 2005

    The findings of livelihoods research conducted in East Africa and Malawi demonstrate that the role of agriculture in contributing to poverty reduction in sub-Sahara African countries is rather more complicated than the apparently straightforward mechanisms portrayed by enthusiasts for agriculture-led growth strategies in the region. Rural livelihoods are diverse and founded on interdependencies between rural and urban areas. These interdependencies have deepened since market liberalisation in the 1980s due to increased price risk, rising input prices relative to output prices, detrimental HIV/AIDS effects on labour and other asset availabilities, environmental deterioration and continuing farm subdivision at inheritance.

    Communities, Commodities and Crazy Ideas: Changing Livestock Policies in Africa

    In the late 1990s a review of aid-assisted livestock projects included an assessment of sustained impact on poorer producers (Ashley et al. 1998). The review looked back over 35 years and analysed documents from more than 800 livestock projects funded by major donors, including the Department foInternational Development (UK), the World Bank, the US Agency for International Development, the European Commission, DANIDA, theNetherlands Development Cooperation and the Swiss Development Cooperation. The majority of these projects were based on a technical transfer paradigmin which constraints facing poor livestock keepers were to be addressed by the development anduptake of technologies, including new methods to control animal diseases, improve livestock breedsor raise production through a variety of other means. However, the lack of sustained impact on the poowas dramatic. In many cases, technologies were developed which livestock keepers either did nowant or could not access due to weak delivery systems. In other cases, the benefits of new technologies were captured by wealthier producers. Partly in response to these problems, a second broa category of livestock projects evolved which aimed to strengthen the capacity of organisations todevelop and deliver novel technologies and services to the poor. These projects focused on government organisations (veterinary and extension services, research centres) and aimed to promote more clientfocused and decentralised approaches. A key project activity was training middle-level managers, researchers and field-level technicians.

    Too Much Inequality or Too Little, Inequality and Stagnation in Ethiopian Agriculture

    The agricultural sector remains our Achilles heel and source of vulnerability …Nonetheless, were main convinced that agricultural based development remains the only source of hope for Ethiopia. (Prime Minister Meles Zenawi 2000).

    A powerful strand of thinking about the causes of long-termagricultural stagnation in Ethiopia defines the problem in terms of inequality. Indeed, it is possible to interpret most Ethiopian agricultural policy initiatives of the past three decades in terms of divergent views on the extent and consequences of rural inequality. This article investigates the hypothesis that (too little rather than too much) inequality has contributed to agriculture’s underperformance, and considers the implications for policy in terms of four alternative pathways for Ethiopian agriculture.

    Making science and technology work for the poor

    By Ian Scoones
    May 2005

    In this viewpoint piece I want to argue that, as currently organised, R and D systems – both public and private – don’t necessarily respond well to the needs of poor people in developing countries. Despite all the hype about the potentials of science and technology for reducing poverty, there are many missed opportunities. Very often poor and marginalised people across the global south do not end up benefiting from S and T. How then should we rethink R and D so that S and T can help in the important challenge to ‘make poverty history’?

    I want to suggest three reasons why currently S and T doesn’t always work for the poor, and illustrate these with three examples from developing country agriculture. First – In the context of globalisation, the dynamics of the market and control by large corporations are increasingly important factors governing access to technologies, both new and old. The lion’s share of agricultural R and D globally is controlled by a handful of large corporations. In the developing world this is increasingly the case, especially with the decrease in public sector capacity for R and D.

    Take agricultural biotechnology and GM crops. A few years ago there was much made of the potentials of GM crops to solve the problems of world hunger. But today, years later, the only GM crops that are being planted in the developing world at scale are essentially cast-off products, developed for other markets. GM cotton or soya were engineered for the commercial farms of the Americas, not for Africa or Asia. Some of these products have found demand and a market and are clearly benefiting some farmers in some places. But, more generally, GM technologies are not addressing the big challenges of drought, nutrient poor soils and so on.

    {jathumbnail off}

    Wild Resources Management in Southern Africa: Participation, Partnerships, Ecoregions and Redistribu

    By William Wolmer and Caroline Ashley

    IDS Bulletin Vol 34 No 3 2003

    In rural southern Africa, access to wild resources is critical to livelihoods and various attempts have been made by policy-makers to increase the income derived from them by poor communities. This article examines the resulting existing and emerging institutional arrangements in the tourism/safari hunting and forestry sectors and assesses their impact on livelihoods. Case studies of wildlife and forestry management initiatives involving communities are drawn from the Sustainable Livelihoods in Southern Africa programme study areas: Eastern Cape (South Africa), Chiredzi District (Zimbabwe) and Zambézia province (Mozambique). Broadly speaking, four types of initiative, with different emphases, can be identified. These are community participation; partnerships or joint ventures between communities and the private sector; ecoregional conservation; and redistribution or restitution. To an extent these reflect different national priorities and contexts and these categories are rarely totally differentiated; overlaps and continuities exist. However, a key trend, particularly in South Africa (which is returned to and looked at in more detail in article 6 in Part III of this Bulletin) is the emergence of a number of policy approaches that seek to link private sector tourism and forestry operations with community or local involvement, usually with an emphasis on “pro-poor” commercial investment.

    Politics and Water Policy: A Southern Africa Example

    By Alan Nicol and Sobona Mtisi

    IDS Bulletin Vol 34 No 3 2003 

    Access to and management of water resources is inherently political. Drawing on fieldwork from the Sustainable Livelihoods in Southern Africa programme, largely undertaken in Zimbabwe, with some additional material from South Africa and Mozambique, this article examines the politics surrounding water resources and policy change in southern Africa and reaches some tentative conclusions of relevance to understanding current policy processes in regional water sector reform.

    Land and Livelihoods: The Politics of Land Reform in Southern Africa

    By Edward Lahiff

    IDS Bulletin Vol 34 No 3 2003

    Southern Africa today presents a wide spectrum of land policies, embracing a variety of forms of redistribution and tenure reform initiatives, utilising methods that range from consensual, market-based approaches to forcible confiscation. Having remained marginal to political debates in most countries of the region for much of the 1980s and 1990s, land and land reform are back on the policy agenda to an extent unknown since the liberation struggles of the 1960s and early 1970s. Recent events in Zimbabwe, in particular, have had strong resonance for political parties and landless people in those countries, most notably South Africa and Namibia, where severe racial inequalities in landholding persist, and struggles over land have become central to external perceptions of the region. Critical questions, therefore, are whether the Zimbabwean case is exceptional or an indication of tensions throughout the region, and whether the heightened political importance of land in the region is a product of changes in the regional or global economy, or a culmination of long-running processes at a more local level.

    The Rural Poor, the Private Sector and Markets: Changing Interactions in Southern Africa

    By the SLSA Team

    IDS Bulletin Vol 34 No 3 2003

    One of the central tenets of much current development thinking in southern Africa is that market-oriented strategies and private sector involvement must be the basis for future economic growth. This has underpinned structural adjustment and economic policy reform policies in the region over the last decade or more. It also underlies the argument for encouraging external foreign direct investment as a motor for growth. However, growing evidence suggests that such a strategy has not paid off. Economic growth rates have been disappointing, private, and particularly foreign, investment has been limited and employment in the formal sector has fallen dramatically. Structural adjustment and market liberalisation has clearly not delivered the developmental benefits claimed of it, and people’s livelihood opportunities and vulnerability have, it seems, respectively declined and increased over the same period.

    Decentralisations in Practice in Southern Africa

    By the SLSA Team

    IDS Bulletin Vol 34 No 3 2003 

    Decentralisation, like good governance or sustainable development, is one of those concepts everyone from the World Bank to top officials in national governments seems to think is a “good thing”. But the meanings attached vary widely. And while donors and governments all want to support it – it is now part of the well-worn lexicon of development clichés – it has palpably failed in many instances to deliver the results claimed of it. Why then is it so popular and what does it entail in practice?  

    Livelihoods in Crisis: Challenges for Rural Development in Southern Africa

    By Ian Scoones and William Wolmer IDS Bulletin Vol 34 No 3 2003

    Southern Africa is in the midst of a major food crisis. Fourteen million people are reported to be at risk. Most commentators agree that since around 1990, livelihoods have collapsed in many areas, with an increasing number of people, particularly in rural areas, vulnerable. But this is 2003, following decades of post-independence development assistance and once-great hopes for the region as both the food basket and economic motor for the continent. What has gone wrong? Has “development” failed? Do we need to radically rethink the paradigms for development in the region? This Bulletin explores some of these questions, drawing on a large body of detailed empirical material from research conducted under the auspices of a three-year collaborative project: the Sustainable Livelihoods in Southern Africa (SLSA) programme, carried out by research partners in Mozambique, South Africa, UK and Zimbabwe, in a series of case study sites.

    IDS Bulletin: Livelihoods in Crisis?

    Livelihoods in Crisis? New Perspectives on Governance and Rural Development in Southern Africa
    IDS Bulletin
    Vol 34 No 3, 2003

    Southern Africa is in the midst of a major food crisis. Fourteen million people are reported to be at risk. Most commentators agree that since around 1990, livelihoods have collapsed in many areas, with an increasing number of people, particularly in rural areas, vulnerable. But this is 2003, following decades of post-independence development assistance and once-great hopes for the region as both the food basket and economic motor for the continent. What has gone wrong? Has “development” failed? Do we need to radically rethink the paradigms for development in the region? By focusing on Mozambique, South Africa and Zimbabwe, a complex story of livelihood change emerges.
    IDSlogoLinks to selected articles to download:

    The Politics of Livelihood Opportunity

    By Ian Scoones and William Wolmer

    IDS Bulletin Vol 34 No 3 2003

    Rethinking Livelihoods

    As previous sections of this Bulletin have shown, the livelihoods of poor, rural people in southern Africa are highly complex, often vulnerable and subject to many uncertainties: biophysical, economic, institutional and political. Any neat prescriptions or models about livelihoods do not stand up for long. Yet, as we have seen, whether in relation to wild resources, land or water and across the countries, certain basic assumptions are repeated. Despite the fact that these do not generally reflect empirical reality, they remain pervasive and influential in the framing of policy.

    Dynamics And Diversity Soil Fertility And Farming Livelihoods In Africa Case studies from Ethiopia,Mali And Zimbabwe

    {jathumbnail off}Dynamics_And_DiversityLocal classification of soil types,

    Gororo, southern Chivi Views on inorganic fertilizers and manures from Chivi communal Area Wetlands and gardening Profdes of case study farmers according to four soil-fertilitychange scenarios experimenting farmers in Chivi communal area Rural livelihoods: identifying avenues for intervention forsoil-fertility management Identifying options for policy and practice: examples from the field sites.

    The reasons for the very significant gap between potential and realized food production in sub-Saharan Africa are multiple and complex. The decline in fertility observed for many areas of soil has been described as the single most important factor. Although this is a challengeable statement it undoubtedly refers to an ever-present reality for the majority of farmers in the continent – that optimizing the nutrient balance on their farms is one of the most difficult of the many agricultural management challenges they face.

    A central feature of this hook is the documentation of the great variety of ways in which farmers have dealt with this problem. More importantly it also gives excellent insight into the ways in which the soil fertility issue interacts with a multiplicity of other factors which impact on farm production – biological, economic, social and political. Scientists, with their strong disciplinary adherences, apply the power of reductive research to these issues and often provide solutions which are valid within their own limits, hut which are difficult to apply because of the lack of attention to these interactive factors.

    The work reported in this book helps to resolve this disjunction between formal scientific method and the realities of farm management. Scientificmethods of varying degrees of formality are used to document and analyse the soil fertility ‘prohlem’, the factors which influence it and farmers’ coping strategies. The replication of this across different countries, environments and communities permits the drawing of commonalities as well as distinctions. The major benefit that may be gained from this is to inform scientists -not just with data hut with insights into the realities of the totality of the farming enterprise. The challenge is then to identify those ‘entry points’ where formal scientific knowledge can he employed to enhance the system as a whole.

    A strong case can indeed be made that soil fertility management is a very significant entry point because of the many interactions it has with othercomponents and because of the long-term nature of the effects that result from changes in soil nutrient status. This book is thus to be recommended not just for the information and insights it provides with respect to the specific issue of soil fertility management, but also because of the major questions it provokes about the application of scientific research to the challenges of sustainable agriculture under the prevailing conditions in African countries.

    Commercialisation of Smallholder Agriculture in Selected Tef-growing Areas of Ethiopia

    {jathumbnail off}{jcomments off}The poverty-reduction strategy adopted by Ethiopia seeks to achieve growth through the commercialisation of smallholder agriculture. The Plan for Accelerated and Sustainable Development to End Poverty (PASDEP), Ethiopia.s strategic framework for 2005/06 – 2009/10, relies on a massive push to accelerate growth. This is to be achieved by efforts in two directions: commercialisation of agriculture, based on supporting the intensification of marketable farm products (both for domestic and export markets, and by both small and large farmers); and promoting much more rapid non-farm private sector growth (MoFED, 2005).

    This study aims to contribute to this plan by identifying factors that can deepen and expand the scope of market participation of smallholders. Commercialisation of agriculture is also a core research theme of the Future Agricultures Consortium.

    Future Agricultures. thematic work on agricultural commercialisation has observed that, in various countries, different modes of commercialisation co-exist and interact with each other (Leavy and Poulton 2007:17): hence the plural term, commercialisations. In Ethiopia, we suggest that the following existing categories of farmer could benefit from enhanced commercialisation (or “market-oriented agricultural growth”). These four categories represent four potentially complementary “pathways” for commercialisation policy.

    1. Smallholder family farms

    • (Type A) Farmers in remote, drought-prone or low-potential areas, generally regarded as “subsistence-oriented” but in fact interacting with markets both as buyers and as sellers. The policy challenge posed by these farmers is to improve their terms of engagement with markets, as well as raising productivity and diversifying livelihoods.
    • (Type B) Small farmers who are already market-oriented, producing crops partly or
    • wholly for sale alongside crops for their own consumption.
    • Such farmers tend to be in locations with favourable growing and marketing conditions, and tend to focus on specific high-value commodities.

    2. Small investor-farmers

    • Individuals or small groups of partners, often educated and urban-based; sometimes agricultural professionals with a background in government or development agencies or former state farms; often investing in farming as a secondary activity. These farmers are referred to in World Bank terminology as “emerging commercial
    • farmers”, suggesting an expected linear trajectory towards larger-scale agri-business. However, we suggest that they are in fact a separate category. In Ethiopia they have started to re-emerge only in the last few years, when access to land for such investments has been made possible.

    3. Large-scale “agribusiness”

    • These are generally capital-intensive enterprises (though they also generate employment), and may be either private or state-owned. Examples are the large.

    Beyond Farmer First

    Beyond Farmer First: Rural People’s Knowledge, Agricultural Research and Extension Practice
    Edited by Ian Scoones and John Thompson
    ISBN 1 85339 250 2
    ITDG Publishing (1994), 301 pages. Price: £12.95

    This book presented a selection of the papers presented at the workshop “Beyond Farmer First”, which took place at the Institute of Development Studies , Sussex , in October 1992.

    Click on the links to view scanned copies of selected sections of the book (by kind permission of Practical Action Publishing).

    BeyondFarmerFirstPart 1: Theoretical reflections on knowledge, power and practice

    Part 2: Methodological innovations, applications and challenges

    Part 3: Transforming institutions and changing policies